If supply and demand equilibrium were an economic โlaw,โ the 1929 and 2008 financial crises would not have occurred. Rather than ready-made theories, economics needs the practical background provided by systems thinking.
This post is part of a reading series on Doughnut Economics by Kate Raworth. To quickly access all chapters, please click here. Disclaimer: This chapter summary is personal work and an invitation to read the book itself for a detailed view of all the author’s ideas. |
For a long time, it was assumed that since rationality is by definition universal, there was a single model of scientific methodology, notably followed by Galileo Galilei and Isaac Newton. The 19th-century economist William Stanley Jevons, for instance, came to think that since physics explains the world from the atomic to the planetary level, the market should tooโfrom the behavior of a single consumer to national and global outputs. In his own words, โJust as we measure gravity by its effects in the motion of a pendulum, so we may estimate the equality or inequality of feelings by the decisions of the human mind. The will is our pendulum, and its oscillations are minutely registered in the price lists of the markets. I know not when we shall have a perfect system of statistics, but the want of it is the only insuperable obstacle in the way of making Economics an exact science.โ1
Overcoming Our Inheritance
“Over in Switzerland,” adds Kate Raworth, “the engineer-turned-economist Lรฉon Walras (1834 โ 1910) had a similar vision, declaring that โthe pure theory of economics . . . is a science which resembles the physio-mathematical sciences in every respectโ, andโas if to prove itโhe started referring to market exchange as โthe mechanism of competitionโ.2 They and others likened the role played by gravity in pulling a pendulum to rest to the role played by prices in pulling markets into equilibrium.” This caricatural vision of markets underpins the widely known diagram of supply and demand.
“What lies behind this iconic pair of crossing lines? Think of a good, any good (letโs say pineapples), and hereโs how it works. The demand curve shows how many pineapples customers will want to buy at each price, given their aim of maximising their utility, or satisfaction. The curve slopes downwards because the more pineapples a customer buys, the less utility they are likely to gain from buying yet one moreโan assumption known as the diminishing marginal utility of consumptionโand so they will be willing to pay a little less for each successive one. The supply curve, in contrast, shows how many pineapples the sellers will be prepared to supply for any given price, given their aim of maximising their profits. Why does the curve slope upwards? Becauseโthe theory goesโif each pineapple farmer has a fixed plot of land, then the cost of growing yet more pineapples on it will start to riseโthatโs the law of diminishing marginal returnsโand so they will require a higher price for supplying each successive piece of fruit.”